Search JC Economics Essays

Custom Search
Showing posts with label economic methodology. Show all posts
Showing posts with label economic methodology. Show all posts

View: If it is too good to be true, it probably isn't always - China's economic statistics


This article is contributed by a kind reader of JC Economics Essays

For many economists and pundits who long believed that China’s incredible provincial and national economic growth figures seemed too good and neat to be accurate, they now have reliable confirmation of their scepticism. While long dismissed as speculation or myth, there is now official news confirming their suspicions. 

What happened?

In 2017, the Chinese government finally admitted that some of its outstanding economic data was made up… which means that some of the economic figures were invented, created, man-made.

Before these shocking revelations, there had been many suspicions: an economic study by Harry X Wu in June 2015 estimated that from 1978 to 2012, China’s Gross Domestic Product (GDP) grew by 7.6%, which would be around 2.6% lower than the official 9.8% economic figure. Perhaps he got closer to the truth than we realise. In fact, it might have been interesting to note that Wu’s (2014) results indicated that Chinese Total Factor Productivity (TFP) growth was negative from 2007 to 2012. Over-building, over-capacity, under-utilisation, and the advance of the Chinese state into private sector markets were also substantially dragging China’s economic growth down.

Yet, despite this doom and gloom in the economic analysis, and the many suspicions, it was reported cheerily in official news that China’s economy expanded by 6.7% in the third quarter of 2016. Economists have sometimes wondered why China’s economic growth figures often look right on track to hit the central government’s target economic growth rates.

And in January 2017, China’s northeastern Liaoning province, which relies on the production of steel as its economic growth engine, reportedly inflated its economic growth figures from 2011 to 2014. 

The sheer scale of this economic deception is quite staggering. This province has a population of about 43 million, which makes it bigger than California in the USA. And this is the first time the Chinese government has publicly admitted to faking official economic statistics at any level. 

Also, what makes this economic case even more surprising is that fiscal revenues in Liaoning were inflated by at least 20% during the same period, and some other economic data there were also fabricated. These actions can be partly attributed to the incentives that rational and utility-maximising Chinese officials face when it comes to economic data. It is said (in Chinese) that Chinese officials produce the economic numbers, and the economic numbers produce officials in turn, which means that massaging economic data can help one get ahead in Chinese officialdom. People respond to economic incentives.

It can be quite breath-taking to think that the economic books are cooked. Some of the faked economic figures are in fact quite dramatic. According to the news agency Reuters, one county in Liaoning province reported an extra fiscal revenue of 847 million yuan (around US$131.3 million) in 2013, more than double the actual figure. And in one of the years, Liaoning’s GDP growth figures were reported at 9.5%, far above the current figure of a mere 2.7%. A pittance! 

And Liaoning had failed to hit government economic targets in key economic metrics in 2016, including economic growth, fixed asset investment, and exports. Since 2014, when Liaoning stopped inflating its economic growth figures, fixed asset investment, an important proxy measure of construction work, had been declining 60% to 70% per annum.

In China today, the falsification of local economic statistics apparently still happens in some areas from time to time, and the government will occasionally issue stern warnings of heavy punishment for those who fake official economic figures. Enforcement seems to remain an issue for China as it continues its economic rise. There are many economic implications: Investors may have to think twice about investing in China; their economic figures have to be taken with a pinch of salt; and most importantly, and surely not just tongue in cheek, there should be many, many jobs for real statisticians in China. 


JC Economics Essays. This is an economics blog with opinions. This economics article was contributed by SS. We thank our readers for their kind and generous personal contribution to this economics blog. The views and perspectives expressed in this article are the author’s own views and based on his own research and are all made in his own private capacity. The sources are available online and also publicly, although the framing and opinions are his. To recap, JC Economics Essays is an economics resource also has useful sample or model economics essays, economics questions, A level Economics examination techniques and economics case studies. Thank you for reading and cheers. 

E-Book: Success in Microeconomics - A Concise Companion to Core Concepts


Hi my dear readers, 

Hope my post finds you well. Kindly allow me to introduce "Success in Microeconomics - A Concise Companion to Core Concepts", a useful resource I have written that explains core theories and concepts in microeconomics in a clear-cut, simple manner, that is easy to master and effective in addressing a variety of microeconomic issues and questions.

In other words, I introduce my effective, simple, powerful guide to Microeconomics, to assist you in your journey towards success in economics. 


As I said in my previous post here on this site, many economics students want high quality economics notes and explanations in key arguments or main points, rather than long verbose academic explanations, with running pages of yet more masses of information, additional case studies, and many more pages of academic appendices and annexes.

In fact, many lecture notes write a mass of academic information rather than focusing on the important theories and concepts needed for educational success - and depth of understanding in economics is as important as breadth, if not more important in examinations.

What would be a useful and relevant economics guide, that had important theories and useful concepts in the subject?

That provision of a useful and relevant economics guide was the fundamental basis of Success in Macroeconomics (kindly see my previous post on Macroeconomics), which would be useful for economics students preparing for the H1/H2 / A level Economics examination. Thank you for your kind support if you have taken up this excellent opportunity.

This e-book on Microeconomics would be useful for students preparing for the A level Economics examination (H1, and H2 Economics, likewise) as well.

What are the secrets to success in Microeconomics?

What are the secrets? What will you learn in this effective, clear-cut, and relevantly concise guide to the most important microeconomic theories and concepts?

(1) Clear, concise definitions to important microeconomic theories and useful concepts, like the central problem of economics, and the price mechanism of demand and supply with elasticities; 

(2) Simply effective step-by-step arguments and methods to construct a convincing economic case, either for or against any economic position, on a range of microeconomic questions on a variety of economic topics or theoretical academic areas

(3) Many common market failures (and how to explain them carefully to score the highest marks possible) and how governments may or may not respond in some policy-problem cases (and how to explain them carefully)

(4) The most useful and powerful economics diagrams that economics students can use in their economics essays, with clear-cut, step-by-step explanations to effectively analyse economic questions, along with simple yet effective tables and figures for easy memorisation

(5) Useful, relevant, theoretical knowledge for crafting strong economic analysis on a variety of relevant contemporary microeconomic issues 

Most importantly, my e-book can be used as a set of simple yet clear-cut economics notes for easy memorisation, for success in economics examinations, giving economics students an edge over others who have to wade through a mass of information and make sense of a bewildering array of information and red herrings.

With concise yet incisive economic arguments, with fundamental microeconomic theories and concepts, this book can be used for time-effective and cost-effective examination preparation, helping economics students prepare for examinations for high achievement in academic success.

Furthermore, this useful microeconomics e-book can also be used as an excellent complementary companion for supplementary reading, because it focuses on microeconomic issues and useful concepts.

I have kindly contributed this e-book to Sallyforth Enterprise, a social enterprise which strongly supports social enterprises, volunteerism, and charity, donating part of all proceeds to charity. Most of the beneficiaries are underprivileged in less developed communities, women, and widows. I always think win-win, and this is win-win indeed!

Thank you very much for your kind, invaluable support.

In Success in Microeconomics, you will be receiving in this e-book:

Pages of Success in Microeconomics:
80 pages including cover pages
Chapters of Success in Microeconomics:
27 chapters
Edition of Success in Microeconomics:
1st Edition
Details of Success in Microeconomics:
Full colour e-book; high resolution tables, figures, diagrams; pictorial and digitally drawn economics diagrams wherever relevant

Do get your copy right now, if you want to learn about success in microeconomics.

Thank you very much for reading and thank you for your kind support!

JC Economics Essays - Our popular, useful, and relevant economics website is mainly about H1, H2, H3 Economics, A level Economics, & economics essays in general, and beyond A level economics essays, this economics site is even for undergraduate and masters level essays (on a variety of interrelated topics such as economics, economic history, and economic development). Thank you very much for reading, and cheers! 

Assess whether a radical reconsideration of the more traditional approaches to policy evaluation employed by economists is called for. [35]


H3 A level Economics Cambridge N2010 Q2 essay response

A controlled experiment generally compares the results obtained from an experimental sample against a control sample. 

“To determine the effectiveness of specific policy initiatives, we need to know how the target populations are likely to respond. This can only be discovered by conducting controlled experiments.” 

In the light of this statement, assess whether a radical reconsideration of the more traditional approaches to policy evaluation employed by economists is called for. [35]

There has been a rise of interest in experiments in economics. Experiments have been proven to be a useful tool for testing some economic theories but their effectiveness can be occasionally doubtful due to limits or flaws in experimental design. While some would argue that we should reconsider the approaches to policy evaluation in economics and adopt empirical methods such as in behavioural economics and experimental economics, some insist that the traditional approaches are still the best method when it comes to policy evaluation, and some kind of middle ground should be reached. 

First, the reasons why economists are interested in experimental economics and behavioral economics are quite obvious. Throughout the development of economics as a discipline, the use of mathematics and deduction usually plays an important role in constructing economic claims. Economics aims to abstract economic phenomena from the complexity of the world and model the behaviors of the economic agents using mathematical tools. During this process, economists make general assumptions of the population and ignore individual anomalies as they feel that according to the law of the large numbers, the aggregate pattern will not be affected by a few cases of anomalies. This method has allowed economists to produce many useful theories. 

However, the limitations are often also obvious. The need to make general assumptions may mean that the theories developed can be incapable of accounting for reality if the assumptions are wrong. Even though Milton Friedman argues that unrealistic assumptions can still produce good economic theories, it seems counter intuitive to claim that an unrealistic assumption can give us more confidence in producing good economic claims than an accurate one. This view is often taken by behavioural economists and experimental economists who want better and more accurate assumptions in economic modelling. 

In fact, the development of behavioral economics and experimental economics show that economists may want to seriously reconsider the methods of constructing economic claims. There are many cases where the traditional way of developing economic theories resulting in inaccurate explanation and prediction. For example, the standard model posits that when the price of an item falls, the quantity demanded will rise to the same extent that the quantity demanded will fall when the price goes up. However, what is observed is that when the price of an item falls, the quantity demanded increases more than the quantity demanded falls when the price goes up. By analysing the results of field experiments and laboratory experiments regarding this anomaly, behavioral economists, Daniel Kahneman and Amos Tversky, explain that this is due to “loss aversion”, which means that people have a stronger tendency to avoid losing than to acquire gains. Losing means paying more than what they used to pay; gaining means paying less than what they used to pay. From this case, we observe that the traditional method can sometimes fail to produce accurate theories, and behavioural economics has moved beyond the rationality assumption in order to construct a better account of this economic phenomenon. As the question states, “we need to know how the target populations are likely to respond”. When it comes to policy evaluation, it is important for the economists to consider the nature of the target audiences. The best way is to select representatives from the target populations and conduct experiments to find out their likely responses to the policy. It seems a better way as compared to the traditional approach which can be wrong or only when the conditions of the theories are satisfied in the real world. 

However, we should also recognize that controlled experiments in the new approaches can be flawed and thus produce inaccurate results. There is a reason why controlled experiments are not usually used in economics. In economic studies, the subject is people who are inconsistent, volatile and ever changing. Since the subject can be exposed to many factors that can easily change their reactions, experimental results can be wrong if the relevant factors are not controlled wisely. For example, in a dictator game where the experimenter researches on the tendency of the agents pursuing fairness in a transaction, the results are different when the experimenter is observing the actions of the volunteers. This example shows that careless experimental designs are likely to distort the experimental results. Even if the experiments are carefully planned and conducted, it may be unwise to generate the result from the volunteers to the target population because there can be self-selection into the experiments and the nature of the target population can be different from the representatives. Besides, it is also showed by research that people are likely to behave differently in experiments and real world decisions. Therefore, flaws in experiments can result in wrong predictions and finally the policy implemented may not produce expected results. 

Finally, we should recognize that both the traditional approach and the new method have their merits, and we should consider the nature of the target population before we consider which way to use in policy evaluation. When a policy is concerning a large population, the traditional way could be better since the theories produced in this way are usually more capable of accounting for behaviors of a large population. It is unwise to use controlled experiments because the population is too large and too risky for generalization of experimental results. However, new findings from behavioral economics and experimental economics can be parameterized into the standard model to better account for reality. For example, loss aversion is incorporated into many theories regarding financial markets to better explain and predict the market trend. Such finding can assist economists to give a more accurate prediction of the likely responses to the policy by the target population. On the other hand, when the target population is small in size, it can be advisable to use controlled experiments to test out the likely responses of the population as they are more likely to be accurate when the conditions of the theories are held in reality. The theory of inequality aversion is a good example to show that theories derived from controlled experiments can yield surprisingly accurate result when the nature of the population can be known. 

In conclusion, the use of controlled experiments can be beneficial in revealing the likely responses of the target population to a policy, but any flaws in experimental design can distort the experimental results. Besides, when a population is large, it can be risky to generalize experimental results to the whole population because the nature of the subjects can be different. On the other hand, the traditional approach also faces the problem of giving wrong judgment when the assumption of ceteris paribus does not hold. Besides, it can fail to give an accurate account of economic behavior when human psychology which can motivate economic actions are constantly ignored in theory construction.  Eventually, what method to choose depends on the size of the target population, the volatility of the economic environment and the availability of information about the target population, but the use of controlled experiments can be introduce beneficial refinement to the traditional approach. 


JC Economics Essays: Once again, as this is the H1/ H2 A level economics examination season, and there is also the upcoming H3 Economics examination, just like in the previous post, I have decided to include a few H3 economics essays. This particular H3 economics essay on economic methodology was contributed by WXN and written under examination conditions of around 1 hour. Special thanks to WXN for his H3 economics contribution to my economics essay site. 

Some areas of improvement for WXN's economics essay could be: More examples could have been given in this essay, and more of the real world context could have been linked to this economics essay. Often times, an essay could benefit from more contextualisation. Also, the division between positive and normative economics could also have been discussed in this essay. Normative economics often lends itself better to economic policy-making and evaluation. Statistics, econometrics, and economic methods such as cliometrics could also have been discussed. The difference between the nature of economics as a social science, and science and mathematics could also have been discussed in this essay. Is economics like a science? Can experimentation play the same role for economics that it has played for the natural and more hard sciences? There are many areas in which this economics essay could have benefited from a wider scope and range.  

However, once again WXN did also do many things right for his economics essay, making all the right moves that make an excellent essay strong. He talked about Milton Friedman, the famous economist, who once wrote a major paper on economic methodology. He also rightly talked about experimental economics and behavioural economics, which are reconsiderations of traditional economic policy-making and evaluation. Perhaps, a distinction between policy-making and economic evaluation could have been made. All in all, given the time constraints and economics examination pressure, this H3 economics essay is quite strong. 

How would you have approached this economics question, and what would you have done differently or better? Please remember to think of ways for further improvement and always question the hidden and implicit assumptions in the question. As this is a H3 economics essay, there will always be room for exploration and discussion, as well as a multitude of perspectives. Demonstrate your reading and your thinking. 

Thank you for reading and cheers!

[Postscript: WXN and his batch of economics students achieved 100% A/B for H2 Economics and 100% Distinction/Merit for H3 Economics in the 2013 economics examinations. They worked hard and performed well, so it is not all my credit. Congratulations!]

“A good theory is one that explains much by little” (Milton Friedman). Discuss whether this is true of economic theories. [35]


H3 Economics Cambridge N2007 Q2 Economics Essay response

“A good theory is one that explains much by little” (Milton Friedman). Discuss whether this is true of economic theories. [35]

Milton Friedman once famously argued that “a good theory is one that explains much by little”, which suggests that a good economic theory should be able to offer an universal account for economic events using simple modelling. The more parsimonious the explanation, the better the economic model, ceteris paribus. This paper argues that such a statement is true as it is in line with the objective in constructing economic theories that are useful in terms of predictive power. However, this criteria does not apply in every situation as sometimes we must rely on economic theories which are more complicated or perhaps on the other hand limited in the range of application.

George Stigler suggested three criteria for us to evaluate all economic theories. These criteria are: tractability, generality, and correspondence with reality. Tractability refers to the easy manipulation of the model and the convenience of fitting the theory into other models. Generality refers to the extent in which the theory can be applied to a large population. The greater the extent, the better the theory is. Correspondence with reality refers to the capacity of the theories in producing explanations and predictions that cohere with the real world. Going with these criteria, we can see that what Milton Friedman suggests can be true. “Explains much by little” means that the theory can be used to account for many economic events or for events in many different situations and contexts. It also means that the theory is not complicated and should be easy to understand. Thus, it can be argued that any theory which fulfills the requirement of “a good theory” by Milton Friedman will be able to meet the “Tractability” and “Generality” requirements by Stigler. Friedman’s statement also seems to suggest that the theory should have an acceptable degree of correspondence with reality, otherwise it cannot be claimed to be able to “explain” the world. Therefore, Friedman’s statement is likely to be true for economic theories. One example to illustrate its validity is the "law" of demand and supply, which is a simple model but one which is able to capture the universal relationship of demand and supply and prices and quantity demanded.

We should further question and closely examine the validity of these three criteria. It is virtually no debate that a simpler model is preferred to a complex model, assuming that they can both produce the same results. Friedman once argued that the process of constructing economic models is to abstract the rich complexity of the reality to relationships of quantifiable variables. The criterion of tractability is thus acceptable. He gives the example of maximization of profits by firms. In firm analysis, economists usually go by the assumption that firms seek to maximize profits. Friedman argues that this assumption allows us to analyze the market easily because all the firms are likely to behave in the same way as they are maximizing their profit since they will lose out due to natural selection if they behave in different ways. Thus, even if the reality is more complex than the theory, this single assumption allows us to abstract the key element of the market and analyze firm decisions with more convenience. Therefore, the criterion of using a simple model to explain economic phenomena is justified. 

Secondly, the criterion of generality is also an important requirement for any economic theory. It is noted that economic aims to capture universal economic behaviors, and therefore is more interested in how does a population behaves in aggregate level. Ultimately, economists aim to develop theories that can explain and predict economic behaviors, especially when it is related to policy making. Firstly, a theory that can account for a larger population is usually preferred to one that can account for a small population. Secondly, a large population enables economists to observe patterns in behaviors which may not be readily obvious in a small population. Therefore, the criterion of generality is also justified. 

In this case, Friedman’s claim that a good economic theory should be able to explain much by little is supported since the statement is in line with the objective in constructing economic knowledge. However, Friedman seems to assume that these two criteria should be placed in priority before the third criterion: correspondence with reality. He could be suggesting that we should not accept theories that can provide accurate predictions but are intractable or limited in the range of applications. 

Correspondence with reality is an important assumption because it is the ultimate test of the theories. Even though Friedman’s statement is true, it should be recognized that these three criteria are difficult to achieve simultaneously, and usually we should compromise one to improve another. For example, theories may predict very accurately but its range of applications is likely to be limited. On the other hand, when the theory is developed to account for a larger population, its accuracy is likely to be compromised. According to Daniel Hausman's reading of J. S. Mill, economics is an inexact science which can offer theories which have loose fit with reality. It seems difficult to achieve the same degree of accuracy in knowledge claims like in natural sciences while ensuring that the law is universal. 

It is sometimes difficult to judge which criterion should be placed in priority. Some argues that providing understanding is also an important requirement for economic theories. Ultimately, economics is the study of human behavior, and people are intuitively interested in understanding the mechanism of an economy. From this perspective, accuracy of economic theory should be placed as the priority and Friedman’s statement does not continue to serve as a yardstick to evaluate a theory. 

In conclusion, Friedman’s statement is in line with the objective of constructing economic claims that are universal, accurate and tractable. However, we may need different economic theories in different situations, and the requirement may not usually serve as a good indicator of good theory, especially in cases where accuracy of claims are taken as a more important quality than tractability and generality. Ultimately, a good theory is one that can serve our interests and is able to assist us in achieving our objectives. Thus Friedman’s claim is only true when we assume that the purpose of constructing economic theories is to provide an account for economic behaviours in the aggregate level. 


JC Economics Essays: As this is the A level examination season, and there is also the upcoming H3 Economics examination, I decided to include a few H3 economics essays in addition to the wide variety of economics papers (H1, H2, A levels, GCE/GCSE/AS) here on my economics site. This H3 economics essay was contributed by WXN and written under examination conditions of around 1 hour. Thank you WXN for your kind contribution. 

Some areas of improvement for this essay could be: a wider scope of exploration could have been conducted. He could have delved into Ockham's razor, the philosophy of positivism and empiricism, or launched into a small case study of theories of the firm where profit maximisation has been roundly criticised by Herbert Simon, Olivier Williamson, and other such famous economists, and the varied empirical studies that flatly contradicted theories. More recent economic theories and studies could also be utilised, such as Schelling's checkerboard model and the famous George Akerlof's lemons model. All of these could have added further depth and rigour to his paper, and made it even better. 

However, WXN did also do many things right, making all the right moves that make an economics essay strong. What do you think were the strong points in his essay? What did he do that you could learn from? For instance, WXN cited famous economists (and used their quotes to further his case, while signalling that he put in effort to study hard) and used a yardstick to evaluate the sentence. Given the time constraints and examination pressure, this H3 economics essay is actually quite strong. How would you have approached this essay, and what would you have done differently?

Thank you for reading and cheers!

[Postscript: WXN and his batch of economics students achieved 100% A/B for H2 Economics and 100% Distinction/Merit for H3 Economics in the 2013 economics examinations. They worked hard and performed well, so it is not all my credit. Congratulations!]

Economics Quotes from Famous Economists


Here are some of my favourite economics quotes from famous economists, as well as famous, popular economics quotes:

Adam Smith

It is not from the benevolence of the butcher, the brewer, or the baker, that we expect our dinner, but from their regard to their own interest. We address ourselves, not to their humanity but to their self-love, and never talk to them of our own necessities but of their advantages.

The Wealth of Nations (1776)

By preferring the support of domestic to that of foreign industry, he intends only his own security; and by directing that industry in such a manner as its produce may be of the greatest value, he intends only his own gain, and he is in this, as in many other cases, led by an invisible hand to promote an end which was no part of his intention. Nor is it always the worse for the society that it was no part of it. By pursuing his own interest he frequently promotes that of the society more effectually than when he really intends to promote it. I have never known much good done by those who affected to trade for the public good.

The Wealth of Nations (1776)

Friedrich Hayek:

The curious task of economics is to demonstrate to men how little they really know about what they imagine they can design. To the naive mind that can conceive of order only as the product of deliberate arrangement, it may seem absurd that in complex conditions order, and adaptation to the unknown, can be achieved more effectively by decentralizing decisions and that a division of authority will actually extend the possibility of overall order.

The Fatal Conceit : The Errors of Socialism (1988)

Ludwig von Mises:

The capitalist system of production is an economic democracy in which every penny gives a right to vote. The consumers are the sovereign people. The capitalists, the entrepreneurs, and the farmers are the people’s mandatories. If they do not obey, if they fail to produce, at the lowest possible cost, what the consumers are asking for, they lose their office. Their task is service to the consumer. Profit and loss are the instruments by means of which the consumers keep a tight rein on all business activities.

John Maynard Keynes:

The long run is a misleading guide to current affairs. In the long run we are all dead. Economists set themselves too easy, too useless a task if in tempestuous seasons they can only tell us that when the storm is past the ocean is flat again. (1923)

The ideas of economists and political philosophers, both when they are right and when they are wrong, are more powerful than is commonly understood. Indeed the world is ruled by little else. Practical men, who believe themselves to be quite exempt from any intellectual influence, are usually the slaves of some defunct economist.

Lord Lionel Robbins:

Economics is the science which studies human behaviour as a relationship between ends and scarce means which have alternative uses.

Milton Friedman:

Inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon in the sense that it is and can be produced only by a more rapid increase in the quantity of money than in output.

I think the government solution to a problem is usually as bad as the problem and very often makes the problem worse.

One of the great mistakes is to judge policies and programs by their intentions rather than their results.

The ultimate goal of a positive science is the development of a "theory" or, "hypothesis" that yields valid and meaningful (i.e., not truistic) predictions about phenomena not yet observed.

Consider the problem of predicting the shots made by an expert billiard player. It seems not at all unreasonable that excellent predictions would be yielded by the hypothesis that the billiard player made his shots as if he knew the complicated mathematical formulas that would give the optimum directions of travel, could estimate accurately by eye the angles, etc., describing the location of the balls, could make lightning calculations from the formulas, and could then make the balls travel in the direction indicated by the formulas. Our confidence in this hypothesis is not based on the belief that billiard players, even expert ones, can or do go through the process described; it derives rather from the belief that, unless in some way or other they were capable of reaching essentially the same result, they would not in fact be expert billiard players.

JC Economics Essays - H1, H2, H3 A level Economics essays and economics tutorial materials. Economics quotes from famous economists can be used in H3 economics essays. 

Sponsored Ads

Please do NOT Plagiarise or Copy Economics Essays

It is one thing to learn how to write good economics essays from sample or model economics essays, but another thing if you plagiarise or copy. Do not copy economics essays.

First, if you are handing in an assignment online, there are checkers online which track sources (such as turnitin). Please craft assignments yourself. Second, if you are handing in a handwritten essay, if you copy, you will not learn and will thus not benefit, nor earn good grades when the real economics examination rolls round. Third, you can always write better essays given time and improvement. Fourth, copying is illegal under most conditions. Do not copy economics essays.

This is an economics site for you to learn how to write good economics essays by reading a range of useful articles on writing, study essay responses and contributions and sample/ model economics essays from students, teachers, and editors. We hope you can learn useful and relevant writing skills in the field of economics from our economics site. Thank you for reading and cheers!