The main macro-economic
objectives of governments include ensuring stable prices and low inflation;
promoting economic growth, both in terms of actual and potential growth; full employment (or conversely low unemployment), and ensuring a healthy balance of
payments (BOP). This paper argues that, on the one hand, while
governments should aim for full employment, full employment should not just be their primary
macro-economic objective.
Unemployment is defined as
the situation where those who are able and willing to work are not able to get
jobs, and full employment involves zero or very low unemployment. (In economic theory,
there are many types of unemployment, such as frictional unemployment and
demand-deficient unemployment, among other examples.) In practice, there will always be some
frictional unemployment as people are looking for new jobs or leaving school. It
can be argued that an unemployment rate of around three percent is close to
full employment. However, it is difficult to determine the full employment
level precisely. Full employment implies that the economy is operating at its
full capacity and there is no output gap or demand-deficient unemployment.
One of the most important
reasons that governments target full employment is that because high
unemployment has various social and economic costs. First, unemployed citizens will earn little income, enabling little consumption as they do not have much
disposable income. Also, the unemployed may become less motivated and less skilled, losing their human capital, which makes it more difficult to find employment in the future, and with a lack
of skills, even with economic opportunities, they cannot get jobs. Also, during
periods of high unemployment, the government will have to spend more on
unemployment benefits and other transfer payments, which may increase
government borrowing. Finally, unemployment may exacerbate social problems such
as crime, vandalism and social alienation, especially if unemployment is
concentrated among young people, for example in Spain during the financial
crisis, when youth unemployment rose massively. Therefore, given the social and
economic costs of unemployment, there are many benefits to achieving full
employment.
To achieve full
employment, Keynesian economists will argue that it is necessary to increase AD
when the economy is in a recession. For example, this can be achieved by expansionary
fiscal or expansionary monetary policy, which means increasing government spending
and reducing direct taxes, and increasing money supply and reducing interest
rates respectively. These expansionary policies will cause AD to increase and
shift to the right, increasing inflation if the economy is at or near the full
employment level, but if there is spare capacity or un-utilised resources there
should only be a limited increase in inflation. Therefore, there is a strong economic
case for aiming for full employment through demand management policies. And the
Phillips curve suggests there is a trade-off between inflation. Therefore,
achieving full employment may cause the side effect of demand-pull inflation.
On the other hand, not
all economists agree that full employment should be the primary objective of
governments. They argue that unemployment cannot be reduced below the natural
rate of unemployment (or NAIRU, or Non Accelerating Inflation Rate of
Unemployment) without causing inflation. Keeping inflation low is also another
objective of governments. Also, any reduction in unemployment below the natural
rate, due to demand management policies, will just be temporary. This is
because the economy will return to the equilibrium level of national output. Therefore,
monetarist economists do not believe there is any point in reducing
unemployment below the natural rate because the only effect will be to increase
inflation. Therefore, according to monetarist economists, attempts to achieve
‘full employment’ of three percent may conflict with other macro-economic
objectives, such as higher inflation. For example, many economies have
an inflation target as the primary objective of their Central Bank, such as the Federal Reserve, and the economic argument here is that if low inflation is achieved, it will enable economic
stability and encourage investment and sustainable growth in the long term.
This is preferable to a government using demand-management policies and causing
economic boom and bust cycles.
However, another way of
aiming for full employment is to use long run supply side policies to try and
reduce the natural rate of unemployment. For example, increased training opportunities and better education can upgrade
the skills of workers and reduce structural unemployment, which is what initiatives such as SkillsFuture aim to achieve. However, these economic policies will take time and it may not be possible for the government to reduce
all unemployment because of imperfect information and bounded
rationality on the part of government agents.
And low unemployment can also
be achieved through keeping inflation low and maintaining steady and
sustainable growth. For example, in the 1990s, both unemployment and inflation
fell due to supply side policies and effective demand management. Therefore,
this suggests that a low inflation target can also be effective in meeting other
objectives.
In conclusion, overall,
low unemployment is a desirable objective, but the economic policies to achieve
this need careful examination because of their limitations and alternative macro-economic
objectives. Increasing AD will only be effective if there is a recession and
spare capacity in the economy. To reduce the natural rate, long run supply side
policies will also be needed. In addition, full employment does not necessarily
have to be inflationary too, as economic growth is sustainable, we could get
close to full employment without inflationary pressures.
JC Economics Essays – This A level economics essay was based on lecture material from a UK economics tutor. It was
in response to an adapted question from the A level Economics syllabus. Also, it was
written during examination conditions of time pressure. What did you learn from
this response, and what economic theories did it tap on to addressing the
economics essay question? However, this economics paper is not very strong in the anti-thesis arguments - what could be done better? How could the other side of the story or narrative be made even better? In addition, there were some economics terms which were mentioned - did the writer define the terms? How could the writer have woven the definition of the terms into the sentences? These critical thinking questions should be asked when you read economics essays.
At JC Economics Essays, we focus on strong economic writing skills, clear and direct explanations of core economic concepts, and the use of relevant, real-world examples to strengthen arguments. And we also strengthen students’ understanding of economics as a subject. We also focus on critical thinking and evaluating economic arguments. Thank you for supporting us, and cheers!
At JC Economics Essays, we focus on strong economic writing skills, clear and direct explanations of core economic concepts, and the use of relevant, real-world examples to strengthen arguments. And we also strengthen students’ understanding of economics as a subject. We also focus on critical thinking and evaluating economic arguments. Thank you for supporting us, and cheers!